Friday, September 19, 2014

The playing field is a cliff

Last week, an Alabama energy utility won a temporary order preventing a newspaper publishing information (legally obtained from public records) about the utility’s pipelines. The utility argued that the order was necessary on national security grounds, because terrorists might find “critical gas infrastructure” and blow it up*. (In unrelated news, Alagasco has recently acquired rights to several bridges on the East Coast and is looking to sell.) For context, the Supreme Court held fortyish years ago that the federal government could not constitutionally block publication of illegally obtained information that had real national security implications.

This is just the latest in a series of restrictions on speech obtained and enforced on the behalf of energy companies. Energy companies that ruin homeowners’ water supplies routinely sue them to keep them quiet. Communities who don’t want massive new fracking projects built nearby get slapped with lawsuits too. (Occasionally a homeowner leading a revolt against an energy company turns out to be the CEO of that energy company - he might do okay, especially since he’s in it with a former House majority leader.)

The problem is that, CEOs and politicians aside, people have very few tools to protect themselves in court. This results in people who are actually suffering harm from a corporation constantly having to look over their shoulders and worry about who they might piss off. Worse yet, when an energy utility screws up and blows up a couple dozen houses and kills a few people, it usually has political connections to limit the consequences of its bad behavior.

But hey, at least we’re protecting the First Amendment rights of some people.
--------------------
* The best part: the Montgomery Advertiser requested this information as part of a pipeline safety series - you know, reporting on things that actually do affect the safety of ordinary Americans.

Sunday, September 14, 2014

I'm not very good at math

Specifically, I have no experience at all with R and have to use it as part of my math class this semester. Focusing on math (along with class readings and other assignments) leaves relatively little time to update this weekend.

Instead, have this charming and reassuring link from recent news. Pay particular attention to the last two paragraphs, where we discover that some person or persons in the U.S. government perjured themselves in order to force Yahoo to reveal its users’ private information. Not holding my breath for any kind of law enforcement response to the felony in question.

Friday, September 12, 2014

"Niceness" and collective action problems

One of the perks of moving to Ann Arbor last month is the ready availability of public transportation. A few weeks ago, I drove twentysomething miles one-way to work, costing me perhaps eight hours a week in unproductive driving time and $40 a week in gas money. Now, I “commute” about three and a half miles one-way on a bus, requiring about twenty minutes each way (call it four hours a week) and not requiring weekly trips to the gas station or pricey central campus parking passes. Pretty sweet deal, even if the buses are a bit crowded sometimes. Maybe a lot crowded. Okay, I’ve been in mosh pits with more personal space and fewer elbows. Seriously, another dozen undergrads want on?!?

. . . Right. On the other hand, nearly everyone on the bus behaves really well. They take up a reasonable amount of space given the ubiquitous backpacks, book bags, and purses; they keep the conversation volume down to a dull roar; practically all of the physical contact is involuntary and inevitable given the standing-room-only conditions in a moving bus. I’m pretty sure at least eight in ten are wearing deodorant and/or bathed recently. The least decorous behavior I’ve seen in the week since classes started involved a student shouting to let the driver know that more people wanted to get off the bus at the current stop, which seemed pretty reasonable given that the driver was closing the doors and letting off the brakes. In turn, the driver thought he could safely close the doors and move on because the people who wanted to get off the bus voluntarily squeezed back to make space for new passengers instead of assertively pushing their way out the door.

This brings me to the actual point of this post. Social scientists often talk about collective action problems in which individuals’ narrowly-conceived self interest leads them to behave in ways that leave everyone worse off in the end. For example, when a fish population is on the verge of collapse due to overfishing, individual boat owners often try even harder to overfish the collapsing population under the assumption that self-restraint just leaves more fish for the competition. Of course, this depletes fish populations even faster and guarantees full collapse (and the resulting destruction of the local fishing industry). In the context of crowded transportation, passengers fighting over scarce legroom demonstrate a similar problem: when resources get more scarce, grabbing all you can and fighting over the rest can seem the only alternative to “everyone else” crushing your kneecaps and/or pinning your seat into its full upright position*. Economists from the center-right leftward** typically tell collective action stories in roughly the same pessimistic way: poor myopic homo economicus can’t properly evaluate long-term costs, so we need at least some government regulation to help the economy recognize long-term costs in the short term.

This isn’t the whole story, though. First, people don’t always behave in the way that a model of narrow self-interest would predict. Experiments show that human players in a one-off prisoner’s dilemma game choose “cooperate” roughly 40-50% of the time***. If this sounds low, consider that the “rational” strategy in a non-iterated prisoner’s dilemma is to always defect (and thus, to cooperate 0% of the time). The vast majority of airline passengers don’t fight over seating, and my fellow sardines on the bus go so far in being “nice” that they fail to clearly signal their intent. So in the best case, people don’t tend to behave as unpleasantly as a rational-choice model with a narrow interpretation of self-interest would imply****. Second, the anecdote of the bus passengers suggests that sometimes we can get a lack of clarity and a failure to coordinate collective action not from short-term self-interest (amounting to mutual hostility) but from what seems to be at least politeness and possibly misplaced altruism.

It should, but can’t, go without saying that the possible solutions for this problem do not include asserting that people should just be more selfish/self-interested. For every case of someone being overly or unthoughtfully polite and inadvertently creating inconvenience (we could add the example of drivers at a four-way stop on a country road repeatedly waving the other on while neither actually drives through the stop), we can find people being obnoxiously assertive and forcing their fellow airplane passengers to detour for a sudden removal of the problem passengers. The inconvenience - or indeed the disastrous environmental harm, when we get to collective problems involving overfishing or climate change - caused by the kind of narrow self-interest that some game theoretic models describe as “rational” is far worse****. Instead, I would suggest that the missing link in the case of the self-abnegating bus passengers is some kind of deliberation, that is, an effort on the part of individual passengers to consider the impact of their actions on everyone involved instead of defaulting to a polite but counterproductive behavior.

--------------------
* But domestic and international flights serving the U.S. carried 826 million scheduled passengers in 2013. So if we assume that fights over seating typically involve two people and that one in a thousand fights escalates to a flight diversion or otherwise makes the news, the three recently-publicized incidents would translate to roughly one scheduled passenger out of every 137,000 getting into a fight over seating.

** I initially learned about the empirical pattern behind “collective action problems” from libertarians advocating transferable fishing quotas and learned the phrase from Greg Mankiw’s undergraduate micro textbook.

*** Sally (1995) in Rationality and Society. You’ll probably need JSTOR access to get the full text.

**** Of course, more complex game theoretic models will give results favoring relatively altruistic behavior. For example, Bob Axelrod (a longtime political science professor here at Michigan, by the way) pioneered the “iterated prisoner’s dilemma” back in the early 1980s, in which the game is repeated and players therefore have to worry about the so-called “shadow of the future” (i.e. the costs of having a reputation as a defector). Axelrod’s book The Evolution of Cooperation (1984) is excellent; I can also recommend a game theory chapter in the 1989 edition (and later) of Richard Dawkins’ The Selfish Gene for a shorter introduction to these concepts.

Thursday, September 11, 2014

Some context

I had planned to start posting after I started grad school here at Michigan with various ideas, working thoughts, and other things I could possibly use in papers at some later point. Instead, I started with the bit of anti-war frustration that you’ll see below and will start with the other stuff sometime this week.


I will post something every couple of days (barring serious technical problems or planned vacations) but make no guarantees as to content. Some of what I write will be blatant appeals for readers to improve my thinking, and I welcome all constructive feedback.

I may update this post with additional information; if so, expect some kind of brief update post permalinking back here to the edited version.

Disclosure: I am a graduate student in political science (2014 cohort) at the University of Michigan Ann Arbor. I am also the president of Rule of Cool Gaming LLC, a small tabletop gaming publisher. All posts here are my own and do not reflect the views, positions, or beliefs of either entity.

All posts on Grounds of Opinion are (c) 2014 Chris Campbell and licensed CC-BY-SA.

Dumb Wars


In 2002, Barack Obama phrased his opposition to the Iraq war as follows: "I don't oppose all wars. And I know that in this crowd today, there is no shortage of patriots, or of patriotism.

What I am opposed to is a dumb war. What I am opposed to is a rash war. . . . A war based not on reason but on passion, not on principle but on politics."

Barack Obama, in concert with neoconservatives, American hegemonists, and war hawks in both the Democratic and Republican parties, is now preparing to commit the United States to a war. This war will involve military intervention, allegedly for humanitarian and liberal internationalist reasons, in a region where previous U.S. interventions have consistently exacerbated and even created humanitarian disasters and illiberal international norms. It will involve either tacit cooperation or explicit material support for Bashar al-Assad's regime in Syria - a regime which has committed every sin of which Saddam Hussein was guilty and which has systematically murdered moderate opposition, thus creating political and military space for the Islamic State. And Obama and his allies will enter this war essentially on the basis of viral videos.

In what way is this war neither dumb nor rash? How is this war grounded on reason? What principles has the Islamic State violated that our soon-to-be-allies in Damascus haven’t?